Supply and Demand by Hubert D. Henderson
page 30 of 178 (16%)
page 30 of 178 (16%)
|
supply. It is supposed to be so drawn that if any point _q_ be taken
upon it, and the perpendicular _q_N be drawn to meet OX, then ON will represent the amount that will be supplied at a price represented by _q_N (or O_k_). Equally clearly this supply curve must slope upwards from left to right, since the higher the price obtainable, the greater will be the quantity offered. Take the point P where the two curves meet, and draw the perpendicular PM to meet OX. Then the third law enunciated at the beginning of this chapter corresponds to the statement that PM or O_m_ will represent the price at which the commodity or service will be exchanged. It can readily be seen that no other price could be maintained. For suppose the price to be less than O_m_, suppose it to be O_k_, then, at this price, ON (or _kq_) will be the amount supplied, and _kr_ the amount demanded. The demand will thus exceed the supply, and the price will tend to rise, i.e. to move upwards towards O_m_. Similarly if we suppose the price to be O_l_, which is larger than O_m_, the supply (_l_R) will exceed the demand (_l_Q) and the price will fall downwards towards O_m_. Thus, again, we have deduced Law III from Laws I and II with the form and precision of a proposition in Euclid. Now, when once the eye has become familiar with this diagram, it ought to be impossible for the mind to lose even momentarily its grip on the fact that demand and supply are both dependent upon price. For these curves do not represent any particular amounts; they represent a series of _relations_ between amount and price; if the price is QN the amount demanded is ON, and so forth. The terms demand and supply in the sense, in which I have been using them, of the respective amounts demanded and supplied are, indeed, strictly meaningless without reference to some particular price. The reference may sometimes be implicit; but, whenever there is a chance of ambiguity, it should be |
|